Interest rates are rising in the US, but in other places they're still below zero - here's what that means

Advertisement

Advertisement
bi graphics negative interest rate explainer lead

Samantha Lee / Business Insider

It's only the second time in a decade. On Wednesday, the Federal Reserve hiked its benchmark interest rate by a quarter of a percent to the range of 0.5% to 0.75%. That number doesn't affect most Americans directly. It's a target for the rate charged when banks lend money to each other overnight.

But it eventually filters through the economy, so when the Fed increases rates, it means mortgages will be more expensive, savings accounts will be more lucrative, and student loans a tiny bit more painful. 

Fed Chair Janet Yellen cited the "considerable progress the economy has made" in the Federal Reserve Board's decision to increase the rate. But historically speaking, 0.75% is still incredibly low. Rates in the US have been hovering near-zero since the financial crisis nearly a decade ago.

It's been worse in Japan and Europe. Japan's economy has been weak for so long that it still has negative rates - it actually charges banks to hold money - a once unheard of phenomenon. The European Central Bank's benchmark rate is also negative, reflecting the slowdown on the continent. In fact, negative rates were so unheard of until recently, academics had to rewrite their textbooks. 

Why go negative anyway? 

If you're a bank, the idea sounds crazy. Why pay someone to hold your cash?

Advertisement

In 1983, when Frederic Mishkin started writing "The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets," his seminal textbook on macroeconomics, he never thought he'd devote much space to the idea of negative interest rates.

"A million years no," Mishkin told Business Insider.

Negative rates were seen as a bizarre thought exercise by academic economists, not something any of us would see in the real world.

 It was "absolutely unthinkable when I started writing this book," Mishkin, a former Federal Reserve governor and professor at Columbia Business School, said.

In fact, it took just about 30 years. And as Mishkin finishes the 12th edition of his textbook, he's devoting a whole lot of space to negative interest rates.

Advertisement

"There's something very shocking about this," Mishkin said. "I have to talk about how negative rates are something that can be very prevalent."

At a basic level, a negative interest rate occurs when a lender pays someone to borrow its money.

The policy has evolved from radical idea to mainstream policy of postrecession governments in Europe and Asia. And in the past, Janet Yellen has said the US will not rule out using them if it needs to.

This is because the Great Recession has rewritten the rules of what can happen - and how central banks can respond - during financial crises. Negative rates could affect just about everyone, notably businesses, banks, homeowners, and anyone with a savings account.

The old way

Advertisement
federal reserve

The US Federal Reserve in Washington, DC.

Centrals banks, like the Federal Reserve in the US or the Bank of England in the UK, control a country's supply of money and set the interest rates that apply when a bank lends to another bank, usually to meet mandates for how much each bank has to keep in reserve.

And for much of the past century, our economic system has worked something like this:

You earn money through your job. You deposit some of that money in your bank. The bank takes a portion and lends it out to customers and stores some of the rest at the Federal Reserve. If it has more at the Fed than is required by regulation, it lends the extra to other banks, which might not have enough in reserve. That's called interbanking lending, and the interest rate we're talking about when we talk about the Fed changing rates applies to that lending between banks overnight. This is actually the most important rate in the country. All other major interest rates are based on it, at least indirectly.

Changing this rate is a kind of lever that the Federal Reserve can pull to make things happen in the economy. If it wants to spur banks to lend, which should boost the economy, it lowers the rate. That eventually makes mortgages and car loans more affordable for consumers. If it wants to slow a raging economy, it raises interest rates.

And for most of our modern financial history it was inflation - the increase in prices - that kept central bankers up at night. As Kenneth Rogoff, an economics professor at Harvard, recently told Business Insider, when he was studying economics in the late 1970s, "Everyone said we'd never grow fast again. Inflation was double digits.

"If you had told me we'd be in some future where central banks were struggling to get inflation up from zero or 1% and they wanted it to be a little higher, I'd say we're living in an alternative universe."

Advertisement

Breaking through the floor

bi graphics negative interest rate explainer sweden

Samantha Lee / Business Insider

Interest rates shattered the 0% floor in some countries since the Recession.

When the Great Recession hit in the late 2000s, central banks did all they could to ease the pain. They lowered interest rates rapidly, a traditional strategy for shoring up free-falling economies. In many places, rates hit zero. When that didn't do enough, some central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, tried nonstandard ways to boost the economy. The Fed started buying back its own bonds with newly created cash - what's known as quantitative easing, or QE.

But there was still one thing that seemed unlikely: going negative. In textbooks like Mishkin's, a 0% interest rate was known as the "zero lower bound." It just didn't seem to make sense to go below that.

Now economists have to rename it.

When QE and a zero interest rate weren't enough in some parts of the world, like Europe and Japan, central bankers did the unthinkable. They started to set interest rates slightly negative.

"You don't do this on a normal sunny day," Rogoff said.

Advertisement

What this means, in practice, is that banks that have money to spare would pay to lend it out. The other bank would actually get paid to take on debt.

So far, Sweden, Denmark, Switzerland, and Japan have tried negative rates with varying levels of success. Sweden's Riksbank was first, in 2009, to take rates below zero. Central banks in Denmark, Switzerland, and the European Central Bank (ECB) eventually followed.

In an important 2012 speech, ECB President Mario Draghi said Europe's central bank would do "whatever it takes" to save the euro. Inflation was too low, and borrowing costs in Spain and Italy were getting out of hand - so high that Spain was about to ask for a bailout.

Today, countries with negative policy rates make up almost a quarter of global gross domestic product, according to the World Bank.


Watch Ken Rogoff explain negative interest rates: 


Low rates for you

Central banks such as the Fed do not set the interest rates that most consumers see in savings accounts, mortgages, and car loans. But the Fed's rates eventually filter through the economy. If a bank can't get much for lending money to other banks through the Fed, then it's not going to pay you much in a savings account.

If rates go negative, then it's conceivable but very unlikely that banks could pass those costs on to consumers. Savings accounts could have a fee instead of paying interest. That wouldn't be fun for savers, but it could incentivize people to spend rather than save.

"It's very hard to obviously get depositors to accept negative interest rates for putting their money in there," said Marc Bushallow, managing director of fixed income at Manning and Napier, which manages $35 billion in assets.

bi graphics negative interest rate explainer flags

Samantha Lee / Business Insider

What's much more likely is that only big banks would be forced to pay to lend money to one another. That would exempt small depositors from paying, but still have some of the stimulus effects that the central banks intend to have. And everyday consumers would have an easy alternative if they were forced to pay to deposit their cash. They can hoard it under the mattress free of charge.

The cash dilemma

Rogoff has come a long way from those days in the '70s when he and his colleagues couldn't imagine central banks even considering negative rates. Now, he says, the experiences of the past few years suggest that central banks will need more room to maneuver in future crises. That could mean rates as low as -4 or -5%.

But that's nearly impossible when people could just keep their money in cash and avoid the costs of depositing money. So, in Rogoff's mind, in order for central bankers to have the option to set significantly negative rates, we have to get rid of cash - or at least big bills above, say, $10 or 10 euros. He writes about this in "The Curse of Cash."

"If they're going to go to a big negative interest rate, why should I take that when I could hold cash?" he said.

Right now, Rogoff says, in places such as Switzerland, the rates are only slightly negative, and the cost to store and insure cash piles is too expensive for insurance companies and the like to keep their reserves in bills.

And with negative rates so new, Mishkin will have to keep a close watch on whether they work to support flagging economies. He may need to update his textbook once again.

NOW WATCH: Ken Rogoff explains why he's been advocating to eliminate the $100 bill